Chimps play fair in the ultimatum game.

نویسنده

  • Manfred Milinski
چکیده

I magine you are given $100.00. You have to propose how to share the money with another person, who can accept, in which case both earn as you have proposed, or reject your offer, in which case neither player gets anything. If both are rational maximizers, the proposer offers one cent, which the responder accepts; one cent is more than nothing and Homo economicus goes for it. This socalled Ultimatum Game (UG) (1) played with humans in many societies (2) usually reveals unexpected fairness. Proposers offer about 40% and responders reject offers below about 20%. A study with chimpanzees, our closest relatives, found them to be pure rational maximizers (3). Proposer chimps offered the smallest amount and responders accepted almost all offers. Is human fairness in the UG unique? In PNAS, Proctor et al. (4) show that both chimpanzees and young children playing the UG split rewards equally. However, in a dictator game (DG), where the partner has no say and simply gets what the proposer proposes, both chimps and children preferred to be selfish. Are chimpanzees fair or selfish? Which differences in the experimental approach of the two chimpanzee studies led to the contradictory results? Jensen et al. (3) adapted an UG design that had been used for humans (5), interacting with an anonymous partner only once in each of four games. In each game the proposer could choose between two allocations: one always being 8 points for self and 2 points for responder, the other consisting of one of four allocations dividing 10 points in various ways. This second option included a fair allocation (5 points for self and 5 points for the responder) and a very unfair one (10 points for self and 0 points for the responder). The human proposers usually offered the fairest allocation and responders rejected unfair offers, especially when the alternative allocation had been fair. In Jensen et al.’s study (3), chimpanzee proposer and respondent sat in adjacent cages. Outside the cages were two sliding trays: one was baited with eight raisins visà-vis the proposer and two vis-à-vis the responder, the other was baited with, for example, five and five raisins, as in ref. 5. Proposers could first choose one of the trays by pulling it halfway to the cages; respondents could accept the offer by pulling the proposed tray the remaining distance (via the rod that came into reach as a result of the proposer’s pull) or could reject it by not pulling at all within a 1-min time frame. All four games were played within a single session, the sequence balanced across subjects. Contrary to human proposers (e.g., refs. 2 and 5), chimpanzees offered the most selfish offer, whereas respondents tended to accept any offer. Surprisingly, even most unfair offers, 10 vs. 0 (i.e., 0-gain for the respondent), were accepted more than 50% of the time. Unlike human responders, who report being angry (6) when confronted with unfair offers, chimpanzee respondents showed almost no signs of arousal (3). Obviously, proposers did not appear to take outcomes affecting the respondent into account and respondents did not care. The authors conclude that this species does not share with humans a sensitivity to fairness. Smith and Silberberg (7) repeated the chimpanzee study (3) with humans in two different treatments. When the responder chose to reject the proposer’s offer, she had to wait for 1 min (or 5 min) until the trial was terminated and the next started. The likelihood of the responder rejecting an offer decreased from 52 to 18% as the period of waiting required to reject an offer was increased. Contrary to previous human studies, rejection in the chimpanzee study (3) was defined by withholding a response for 1 min in a repeated-trials design, which lowers the rate of raisins consumed per session. The responder chimp could start the next session immediately by accepting the offer, which thus paid off even if it was a zero offer (7). Smith and Silberberg argue that if species differences in time horizons are accommodated, Jensen et al.’s (3) ape data are reproducible with humans. However, we still do not know whether chimpanzees can be fair in the UG. Proctor et al.’s study (4) with chimpanzees used a different design. As in all previous human studies, Proctor et al. used a kind of money: colored tokens that cannot be consumed but must be traded for something of value. “We chose to use tokens representing food rather than food directly to prevent their choices from being influenced by prepotent responses to seeing food” (4). Again, two chimpanzees were placed in two adjacent testing rooms separated by a mesh panel. Each time, six rewards, banana slices, were lined up on a tray in front of the chimpanzees. The proposer was presented with a choice of two tokens, one representing an equal split of the rewards (3/3) and the other an unequal split favoring the proposer (5/1). The proposer passed the selected token to the respondent through the mesh panel (Fig. 1). The respondent either returned the token to the experimenter to accept the offer or did not return it for 30 s, hence rejecting the offer. On acceptance, the six banana slices were visibly divided on the tray according to the token selected. The tray was then pushed within reach of the chimpanzees so that each could collect its reward. Chimpanzees received two test sessions of 12 trials each on two different days. Although proposers had a significant initial preference for the selfish token, they overall preferred the equitable (5/5) token in 75% of the trials. Interestingly, also in this study, respondents accepted all offers. The results of the UG were compared with those of a preference test that all individuals had to perform before the UG. This test resembled a DG, where the respondent could not influence outcomes. In the DG, human “proposers” usually maximize their own gain. Each chimpanzee was paired with a “foil” partner, who was naïve to the conditions of the task. As in the UG, the rewards were lined up in a tray. The subject chimpanzee was given the choice between the two tokens to return to the experimenter (it had not yet Fig. 1. The proposer chimp has chosen the “equity” token and offers it to the respondent chimp. If the respondent accepts the offer, the six banana slices on the tray outside the cages are visibly divided according to the token selected and the reward made available to the chimps (see commentary text and ref. 4) for details).

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

منابع مشابه

The Evolution of Fairness under Assortative Matching in Ultimatum Mini Game

This paper shows that, under assortative matching rule, the fair action can be maintained in ultimatum mini game on the evolutionary dynamics. If matching is random, then the selfish action generates higher payoff than fair action and the selfish individuals, who play rationally, are always survived on the replicator dynamics. If, however, matching is assortative, then fair responders are easy ...

متن کامل

The Social Ultimatum Game

The Ultimatum Game is a key exemplar that shows how human play often deviates from “rational” strategies suggested by game-theoretic analysis. One explanation is that humans cannot put aside the assumption of being in a multi-player multiround environment that they are accustomed to in the real world. We introduce the Social Ultimatum Game, a multi-player multi-round version of the classical Ul...

متن کامل

The evolution of fairness through spite.

The presence of apparently irrational fair play in the ultimatum game remains a focal point for studies in the evolution of social behaviour. We investigate the role of negative assortment in the evolution of fair play in the ultimatum game. Spite-social behaviour that inflicts harm with no direct benefit to the actor-can evolve when it is disproportionally directed at individuals playing diffe...

متن کامل

Fairness versus reason in the ultimatum game.

In the Ultimatum Game, two players are offered a chance to win a certain sum of money. All they must do is divide it. The proposer suggests how to split the sum. The responder can accept or reject the deal. If the deal is rejected, neither player gets anything. The rational solution, suggested by game theory, is for the proposer to offer the smallest possible share and for the responder to acce...

متن کامل

Neural mechanism of proposer's decision-making in the ultimatum and dictator games☆

Previous studies have demonstrated that reactions to unfair offers in the ultimatum game are correlated with negative emotion. However, little is known about the difference in neural activity between a proposer's decision-making in the ultimatum game compared with the dictator game. The present functional magnetic resonance imaging study revealed that proposing fair offers in the dictator game ...

متن کامل

Defense mechanisms of empathetic players in the spatial ultimatum game.

Experiments on the ultimatum game have revealed that humans are remarkably fond of fair play. When asked to share an amount of money, unfair offers are rare and their acceptance rate small. While empathy and spatiality may lead to the evolution of fairness, thus far considered continuous strategies have precluded the observation of solutions that would be driven by pattern formation. Here we in...

متن کامل

ذخیره در منابع من


  با ذخیره ی این منبع در منابع من، دسترسی به آن را برای استفاده های بعدی آسان تر کنید

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

عنوان ژورنال:
  • Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America

دوره 110 6  شماره 

صفحات  -

تاریخ انتشار 2013